Insider's Game

Selected writings by David Fiderer

Fatal Flaw In Proposal For Housing Finance Reform

First published in National Mortgage News on April 22, 2014

If you saw “Titanic” you probably understand subordination, and the reason why there was a meltdown in September 2008. And you might also understand why Johnson-Crapo invites a similar disaster going forward.

More than a century ago on the Titanic, the captain set access to lifeboats according to a hierarchy of classes: First class women and children first. As a result, the mortality rate among women in first class was not catastrophic, whereas it was for men traveling in steerage, and for those working in the boiler room.

 

Subordination Caused the September 2008 Meltdown

 

Private-label residential mortgage securitizations are designed around a strict hierarchy of classes, which determine, not loss of life, but loss of principal. These modern marvels of financial engineering had purportedly found a way to contain any potential damage, by making sure that all suffering was borne first by the lower classes.

 

For tranches that absorbed up to the first 10% loss in any given mortgage pool, the results might be catastrophic, but the senior tranches would feel no pain.

 

Private-label deals represented a small subsector, about 20%, of the $11 trillion residential mortgage market as of yearend 2007. And the deeply subordinate tranches represented a small sliver of that subsector. And in 2007 if you hadn’t paid attention, it might seem like catastrophic losses, contained within a small sliver of a subsector, would not have much of a ripple effect.

 

Had the lower classes been spread and disbursed throughout the vast universe of the institutional debt markets, the catastrophic losses borne by a sliver of a mortgage subsector might not have had much of a ripple effect.

 

Unfortunately, these risk exposures were concentrated among a relative handful of major institutions that didn’t think about the risks of subordination.

 

For the most part, those deeply subordinated tranches were never actively traded in the secondary markets. Rather, they were warehoused, bundled and sold off as portfolio investments known as collateralized debt obligations. CDO structures were designed and sanctioned by the ratings agencies, who never gave much thought about the impact of subordination in a mortgage bond portfolio.

 

Within any private-label deal, the geographic diversification is a lot less than meets the eye. It inevitably follows that the senior tranches get paid down from the homeowners that prepay earliest, those individuals who refinance whenever they find it advantageous to do so. The subordinate tranches are more reliant on homeowners who are unable to refinance, and are more likely to be underwater because of prices in the local market. Think of it this way, if you sold travel insurance on the Titanic, you didn’t really diversify your risk by selling more policies to passengers traveling in steerage.

 

Top executives at large firms were ignorant of the risks from deeply subordinated mortgage debt embedded within CDOs. In case you forgot, AIG, Citigroup, UBS, Merrill Lynch, MBIA and AMBAC all faced the specter of insolvency because their collective risk exposure to subprime CDOs exceeded $300 billion.

 

The losses from those particular CDOs, about 3% of all mortgage debt, exceeded all the credit losses from $4.8 trillion worth of mortgage debt financed by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac as of yearend 2007.

 

Because CDO losses had impaired their own capital, and because they faced with a crisis of confidence among their counterparties, AIG, Citigroup, UBS, B of A/Merrill, MBIA and AMBAC and others were forced to cut back on credit they extended to customers. So their actions drained liquidity from the marketplace, creating a downward spiral and, well, you know the rest.

 

All this was traceable to a tiny percentage of the nation’s overall mortgage debt, where a very high concentration of risk and loss was found among tranches in the bottom 10% of their deals’ capital structure.

 

Johnson-Crapo: Deju Vu All Over Again

 

Johnson-Crapo reflects a similar kind of obliviousness to the risks of subordination. In a nutshell, the bill would demolish Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, and the types of housing finance they offer, and replace them with a system offering a new type of residential mortgage securitization, one which is insured by combination of private parties and the federal government.

 

Private parties would insure the first 10% loss, and any losses above that threshold would be insured by the federal government. In effect, these would be two-tranche securitizations, with a risk-free senior tranche representing 90% of the total, and a second tranche assuming private credit risk, which is subordinate to 90% of the deal’s capitalization.

 

To be clear, Johnson-Crapo securities are not like those toxic CDOs. Structurally, they are far riskier. CDOs were packed with investment-grade tranches that, though they were subordinate to 90% of a deal’s capitalization, remained structurally senior to the sub-investment grade or equity tranches, which provided a 4% cushion. Johnson-Crapo securities have no equity cushion.

 

These deeply subordinated tranches are the only reference point we have for estimating whether the Johnson-Crapo system will be successful. Private mortgage insurers may be adept at taking on subordinate credit risk, but almost all of their business is on a loan-level basis, not on a portfolio basis. And history shows that the private mortgage insurers’ collective risk appetite had its ebb and flow. By contrast, Fannie and Freddie have served as a buffer to market cyclicality.

 

Johnson-Crapo Versus GSE Securitizations: Which is better at diversifying risk?

 

Here’s an inconvenient truth: It is simply impossible for private-label deal to attain anything close to the level of risk diversification by a GSE securitization. Forget about any kind of implicit or explicit government support, just look at the deals’ structure and their performance record. GSE securitizations benefit from corporate guarantees, so they are, by definition, exponentially safer than private-label deals.

 

When you invest in a private-label deal, your only source of repayment is a static pool of mortgage loans in liquidation. If the quality of the loans in the pool is worse than expected; if the loans were booked at the peak of the cycle and home prices are moving downward; if loans prepay faster than expected so that interest income will not offset credit losses, investors in that particular pool are stuck. And the investors who suffer the most are those near the bottom of the tranche hierarchy, those that assume the first 10% loss on any given deal.

 

Investors in GSE securitizations are not reliant on the performance of one mortgage pool. If one pool generates insufficient cash flow to repay investors’ interest and principal, the shortfall will be replenished by corporate income earned elsewhere.

 

Can investors rely on Fannie and Freddie’s profitability? We only have history to go by, and the GSEs underwriting standards have proved to be exponentially superior to that of any other segment in the industry.

 

The key to successful lending and investing is risk diversification, and the key to stable markets is the broad distribution of risk among institutional investors. The Johnson-Crapo system, which relies so heavily on deeply subordinated debt, obviates those goals.